13 Imperfect
In previous chapters, we have discussed the power of free markets to allocate resources efficiently. However, the magic of the price system actually requires markets to be perfect. Unfortunately, perfect competition is never found in the real world. However, it is a useful theoretical model that serves as a reference point for analyzing real-world markets. It provides valuable insights into market functioning and informs policymakers on how to address instances of market failure, where at least one assumption of perfect markets is not met.
Usually, in real markets, the conditions of perfect markets are not given. However, that does not mean that such imperfect markets perform worse than non-market-based solutions of centrally planned economies, for example.
Theory would predict that if firms in an industry make some profits, new firms will enter the market or existing firms will produce more, which both yield an increase in supply. That, in turn, will drive down market prices until all firms earn zero profits and no more firms have an incentive to enter the market. In equilibrium, total revenue equals total cost. Thus, firms do not make profits. Firms can only make profits if they have some sort of competitive advantage and hence are not price takers, which would contradict assumption 1. The most extreme form of competitive advantage is a monopoly. It describes a situation where one firm is the only provider of a certain good or service. This firm can set prices and control the supply of the good or service completely. We will discuss that extreme case in the next section.
13.1 Theorems of welfare economics
There are two fundamental theorems of welfare economics. The first states that a market in equilibrium under perfect competition will be Pareto optimal in the sense that no further exchange would make one person better off without making another worse off. The requirements for perfect competition are as follows:
- There are no externalities and no transaction costs, and each actor has perfect information.
- Any efficient allocation of resources can be achieved through competitive markets, given the right redistribution of resources.
13.2 Types of imperfect market structures
To develop principles and make predictions about markets and how producers will behave in them, economists have developed numerous models of market structure, including the following:
- Monopolistic competition: also called competitive market, where there are a large number of firms, each having a small proportion of the market share and slightly differentiated products.
- Oligopoly: a market dominated by a small number of firms that together control the majority of the market share.
- Duopoly: a special case of an oligopoly with two firms.
- Monopsony: when there is only one buyer in a market.
- Monopoly: where there is only one provider of a product or service.
- Natural monopoly: a monopoly where economies of scale cause efficiency to increase continuously with the size of the firm. A firm is a natural monopoly if it can serve the entire market demand at a lower cost than any combination of two or more smaller, more specialized firms.
- Perfect competition: a theoretical market structure featuring no barriers to entry, an unlimited number of producers and consumers, and a perfectly elastic demand curve.
As one assumption of the perfect free market is that there is competition, it is evident that if there is just one or a few competitors, this assumption is not fulfilled. In the following, we discuss what happens to markets that don’t have perfect competition.
13.3 Price controls
13.3.1 Maximum price
A legal maximum price, set to protect consumers, establishes an upper limit for the sale of a good. One example is price fixing in rental apartments. It is ineffective if set above the equilibrium price (see Figure 13.1); it becomes binding when placed below the equilibrium price (see Figure 13.2). This can lead to deadweight loss due to missed mutually beneficial transactions.
13.3.2 Minimum price
A legal minimum price is a rule that sets the lowest price for a product, protecting sellers. For example, minimum wage protects the seller of labor time. Only when this minimum price is higher than the normal price is it binding and affects the market.
13.3.3 Price controls
Analyze the two scenarios above. Can you sketch in both plots consumer and producer surplus? Who is better off? Who is worse off? And does overall welfare increase or decrease?
13.3.4 Taxes
Taxes change how things are bought and sold. When there’s a tax, people who buy things pay more, and people who sell things receive less money, no matter who the tax is on. Tax incidence shows how the burden of the tax is divided between buyers and sellers.
The tax has several effects:
- Quantity of goods sold decreases.
- Sales decrease after the tax is applied.
- The tax burden is shared between buyers and sellers, no matter who the tax is imposed on.
- There is a loss of welfare (deadweight loss).
13.4 Subsidies
Subsidies are like negative taxes, producing the opposite impacts of taxes, which include:
- More quantity being bought and sold.
- A boost in total sales due to the subsidy.
- The benefits are shared between buyers and sellers, regardless of who receives the subsidy.