21  Comparative advantage

Learning objectives
  • Less-developed countries can compete in international markets even if they are less productive in producing everything. In other words, opening to trade is beneficial for countries that have an absolute disadvantage in the production of all goods.
  • Both, developed and less-developed countries can gain from international trade.
  • Specialization in production increases the price of exported goods for that country. As a result, prices converge.
  • A discussion of national competitiveness is not useful through the lens of the Ricardo theorem.

Recommended reading: Suranovic (2012, Chapter 2)

Figure 21.1: This painting shows Ricardo, aged 49 in 1821.

Source: National Portrait Gallery

David Ricardo (1772-1823), one of the most influential economists of his time, had a simple idea that had a major impact on how we think about trade. In Ricardo (1817), he argued that bilateral trade can be a positive-sum game for both countries, even if one country is less productive in all sectors, if each country specializes in what it can produce relatively best.

Ricardo, D. (1817). On the principles of political economy and taxation. John Murray.

1 Actually, strictly speaking, this is not correct, since the original description of the idea can already be found in Torrens (1815). However, David Ricardo formalized the idea in his 1817 book using a convincing and simple numerical example. For more information on this, as well as a great introduction to the Ricardian model and more, I recommend Suranovic (2012).

Torrens, R. (1815). An essay on the external corn trade.

He introduced the theory of comparative advantage that is still an important corner stone of the modern theory of international trade1 The theory is also known as the Ricardian model. It refers to the ability of one party (an individual, a firm, or a country) to produce a particular good or service at a lower opportunity cost than another party. In other words, it is the ability to produce a product with the highest relative efficiency, given all other products that could be produced. In contrast, an absolute advantage is defined as the ability of one party to produce a particular good at a lower absolute cost than another party.

Figure 21.2: Comparative advantage: Specialize and exchange

As shown in Figure 21.2, the concept of comparative advantage is quite simple. Two parties can increase their overall productivity by sharing the workload based on their respective comparative advantages. Once they have achieved this increase in productivity, they must agree on how to divide the resulting output. Of course, both parties must benefit compared to a scenario in which they work independently.

21.1 Defining absolute and comparative advantages

A subject (country, household, individual, company) has an absolute advantage in the production of a good relative to another subject if it can produce the good at lower total costs or with higher productivity. Thus, absolute advantage compares productivity across subjects but within an item.

A subject has a comparative advantage in the production of a good relative to another subject if it can produce that good at a lower opportunity cost relative to another subject.

Let me explain the idea of the concept of comparative advantage with some examples:

Old and young

Two women live alone on a deserted island. In order to survive, they have to do some basic activities like fetching water, fishing and cooking. The first woman is young, strong and educated. The second is older, less agile and rather uneducated. Thus, the first woman is faster, better and more productive in all productive activities. So she has an absolute advantage in all areas. The second woman, in turn, has an absolute disadvantage in all areas. In some activities, the difference between the two is large; in others, it is small. The law of comparative advantage states that it is not in the interest of either of them to work in isolation: They can both benefit from specialization and exchange. If the two women divide the work, the younger woman should specialize in tasks where she is most productive (for example, fishing), while the older woman should focus on tasks where her productivity is only slightly lower (for example, cooking). Such an arrangement will increase overall production and benefit both.

The lawyer’s typist

The famous economist and Nobel laureate Paul Samuelson (1915-2009) provided another example in his well-received textbook of economics, as follows: Suppose that in a given city the best lawyer also happens to be the best secretary. However, if the lawyer focuses on the task of being a lawyer, and instead of practicing both professions at the same time, hires a secretary, both the lawyer’s and the secretary’s performance would increase because it is more difficult to be a lawyer than a secretary.2

2 In the first eight editions the example comprised a male lawyer who was better at typing than his female secretary, but who had a comparative advantage in practising law. In the ninth edition published 1973, both lawyer and secretary were assumed to be female (see Backhouse & Cherrier, 2019). Unfortunately, women are still discriminated against in introductory economics textbooks (see Stevenson & Zlotnik, 2018).

Backhouse, R. E., & Cherrier, B. (2019). Paul Samuelson, gender bias and discrimination. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 26(5), 1053–1080.
Stevenson, B., & Zlotnik, H. (2018). Representations of men and women in introductory economics textbooks. AEA Papers and Proceedings, 108, 180–185.

21.2 Autarky: An example of two different persons

Assume that A and B want to produce and consume \(y\) and \(x\) respectively. Because of the complementarity of the two goods, each must be consumed in combination with the other. The utility function of both persons is \(U_{\{A;B\}}=min(x,y)\). Both persons work for 4 time units, that is, their units of labor are \(L_A=L_B=4\). A needs 1 units of labor to produce one unit of good \(y\) and 2 units of labor to produce one unit of good \(x\). B needs \(\frac{4}{10}=0.4\) units of labor to produce one unit of good \(y\) or good \(x\). Thus, their labor input coefficients, which measure the units of labor required by a subject to produce one unit of good, are \(a^A_y=1, a^A_x=2, a^B_y=0.4, a^B_x=0.4\):

input coefficient (\(a\)) A B
Good \(y\) 1 0.4
Good \(x\) 2 0.4

Spending all her time in the production of \(y\), A can produce \(\frac{L_A}{a_y^A}=\frac{4}{1}=4\) units of \(y\) and B can produce \(\frac{L_B}{a_y^B}=\frac{4}{0.4}=10\) units of \(y\). Spending all her time in the production of \(y\), A can produce \(\frac{L_A}{a_x^A}=\frac{4}{2}=2\) units of \(x\)and B can produce \(\frac{L_B}{a_x^B}=\frac{4}{0.4}=10\) units of \(x\). Knowing this, we can easily draw the production possibility frontier curves (PPF) of person A and B as shown in Figure 21.3.

Figure 21.3: The production possibility frontier in autarky

In autarky, both person maximize their utility: Individual A can consume \(\frac{4}{3}\) units of each good and individual B can consume \(5\) units of each good. The respective indifference curves are drawn in dashed blue lines in Figure 21.3.

Exercise 21.1 Indifference curves for perfect complementary goods

  1. Name some real world examples of goods that are perfectly complementary.
  2. The blue dashed lines in Figure 21.3 represent the indifference curves of individual A and B. The upward sloping dashed black line is denoted with ``possible consumption path’’. Explain, why is it not correct–in strict sense–to name it like that?

21.2.1 Can person A and B improve their maximum consumption with cooperation?

Let us assume the two persons come together and try to understand how they can improve by jointly deciding which goods they should produce. If we assume that both persons redistribute their joint production so that both have an incentive to share and trade, we can concentrate on the total production output. Their joint PPF curve can then be drawn in two ways:

  1. Person A specializes in good \(x\), then the joint production possibilities are presented in Figure 21.4.
Figure 21.4: World PFF, A specializes in \(x\)

If A produces only good \(x\), as shown in Figure 21.4, we see that A and B can consume a total of 6 units of goods \(x\) and \(y\). This is less in total than in autarky, where A can consume \(\frac{4}{3}\) units of each good and person B can consume \(5\) units of each good, giving a combined consumption of \(\frac{19}{3}=6,\bar{6}\).

  1. Person A specializes in good \(y\), then the joint production possibilities are presented in Figure 21.5.
Figure 21.5: World PFF, A specializes \(y\)

If A produces only good \(y\), as shown in Figure 21.5, we see that A and B can consume a total of 7 units of goods \(x\) and \(y\). Thus, both can be better off compared to autarky, since the total quantity distributed is larger. Thus, we have an Pareto improvement here because at least one person can be better off compared to autarky.

Figure 21.6: World PFF in autarky when A specialize in producing good \(y\)

In Figure 21.6, the three possible consumption scenarios are marked with a dot and the PPFs of person A specializing in the production of good \(x\) (\(PPF_{A\rightarrow x}\)) or good \(y\) (\(PPF_{A\rightarrow y}\)) are also drawn. The scenario with person A specializing in the production of good \(y\) is the output maximizing solution.

21.2.2 Optimal production in cooperation

In order to produce the most bundles of both goods, the optimal cooperative production is

production in cooperation A B
Good \(y\) 4 3
Good \(x\) 0 7

21.2.3 Check for absolute advantage

Employing 10 units of labor B can produce more of both goods and hence has an absolute advantage in producing \(x\) and \(y\). Formally, we can proof this by comparing the input coefficients of both countries in each good:

absolute advantage A B
Good \(y\) \(a_y^A=1\) > \(0.4=a_y^B\) \(\Rightarrow\) B has an absolute advantage in good \(y\)
Good \(x\) \(a_x^A=2\) > \(0.4=a_x^B\) \(\Rightarrow\) B has an absolute advantage in good \(x\)

21.2.4 Check for comparative advantage

The slope of the PPFs represent the marginal rate of transformation, the terms of trade in autarky and the opportunity costs of a country. The opportunity costs are defined by how much of a good \(x\) (or \(y\)) a person (or country) has to give up to get one more of good \(y\) (or \(x\)). For example, A must give up \(\frac{a_x^A}{a_y^A}=\frac{1}{2}=0.5\) of good \(x\) to produce one more of good \(y\). Thus, A’s opportunity costs of producing one unit of \(y\) is the production foregone, that is, a half good \(x\). All opportunity costs of our example are:

opportunity costs of producing … A B
…1 unit of good \(y\): \(\frac{a_y^A}{a_x^A}=\frac{1}{2}=0.5\) (good x) \(\frac{a_y^B}{a_x^B}=\frac{0.4}{0.4}=1\) (good x)
…1 unit of good \(x\): \(\frac{a_x^A}{a_y^A}=\frac{2}{1}=2\) (good y) \(\frac{a_x^B}{a_y^B}=\frac{0.4}{0.4}=1\) (good y)

Person A has a comparative advantage in producing good \(y\) since A must give up less of good \(x\) to produce one unit more of good \(y\) than person B must. In turn, Person B has a comparative advantage in producing good \(x\) since B must give up less of good \(y\) to produce one unit more of good \(x\) than person B must give up of good \(y\) to produce one unit more of good \(x\). Thus, every person has a comparative advantage and if both would specialize in producing the good in which they have a comparative advantage and share their output they can improve their overall output as was shown in Figure 21.6.

An alternative and more direct way to see the comparative advantages of A and B, respectively, is by comparing the two input coefficients of A with the two input coefficients of B: \[\begin{align*} \frac{a^A_y}{a^A_x} &\lesseqqgtr \frac{a^B_y}{a^B_x} \quad \Rightarrow \quad \frac{1}{2} <\frac{0.4}{0.4}. \end{align*}\] Thus, A has a comparative advantage in \(y\) and B in \(x\).

Comparative advantage: Definition

Economic subjects (e.g., individuals, households, firms, countries) should specialize in the production of that good in which they have a comparative advantage, that is, the ability of an economic subject to carry out a particular economic activity (e.g., producing goods) at a lower opportunity cost than a trade partner.

  • \(\frac{a^A_y}{a^A_x} > \frac{a^B_y}{a^B_x} \Rightarrow\) country A (B) has a comparative advantage in good x (y)
  • \(\frac{a^A_y}{a^A_x} < \frac{a^B_y}{a^B_x} \Rightarrow\) country A (B) has a comparative advantage in good y (x)
  • \(\frac{a^A_y}{a^A_x} = \frac{a^B_y}{a^B_x} \Rightarrow\) no country has a comparative advantage

21.2.5 Trade structure and consumption in cooperation

If A specializes in the production of \(y\), she must import some of good \(y\), otherwise she cannot consume a bundle of both goods as desired. In turn, B wants to import some of the good \(y\). B will not accept to consume less than 5 bundles of \(y\) and \(x\) as this was his autarky consumption. Thus, B wants a minimum of 2 units of good \(y\) from A. A will not accept to give more than \(4-\frac{4}{3}=2\frac{2}{3}\) items of good \(y\) away and he wants at least \(\frac{4}{3}\) items of good \(x\). Overall, we can define three trade scenarios:

  1. All gains from cooperation goes to A (see Figure 21.7 and Table 21.1);
  2. All gains from cooperation goes to B (see Table 21.2); or
  3. The gains from specialization and trade are shared by A and B with a trade structure between the two extreme scenarios.
Table 21.1: : Consumption and trade when all gains from cooperation goes to A
(a) Consumption
A B
Good \(y\) 2 5
Good \(x\) 2 5
(b) Exports and imports of goods
A B
Good \(y\) -2 2
Good \(x\) 2 -2
Table 21.2: : Consumption and trade when all gains from cooperation goes to B
(a) Consumption
A B
Good \(y\) \(\frac{4}{3}\) \(5\frac{2}{3}\)
Good \(x\) \(\frac{4}{3}\) \(5\frac{2}{3}\)
(b) Exports and imports of goods
Trade A B
Good \(y\) \(-\frac{2}{3}\) \(\frac{2}{3}\)
Good \(x\) \(\frac{4}{3}\) \(-\frac{4}{3}\)

Each of the three cases yield a Pareto-improvement, that is, none gets worst but at least one gets better by mutually decide on production and redistribute the joint output. In the real world, however, it is often difficult for countries to cooperate and decide mutually on production and consumption. In particular, it is practically difficult to enforce redistribution of the joint outcome so that everyone is better off. So let’s examine whether there is a mechanism that yields trade gains for both trading partners.

Figure 21.7: Bilateral trade with one winner

21.3 The Ricardian model

To understand the underlying logic of the argument, let us formalize and generalize the situation of two subjects and their choices for production and consumption.

In particular, the Ricardian Model build on the following assumptions:

  • 2 subjects (A,B) can produce 2 goods (x,y) with
  • technologies with constant returns to scale. Moreover,
  • production limits are defined by \(y^i Q_y^i+ a_x^i Q_x^i=L^i\)$, where \(a^i_j\) denotes the unit of labor requirement for person \(i \in \{A,B\}\) in the production of good \(j\in \{x,y\}\) and \(Q^i_j\) denotes the quantity of good \(j\) produced by person \(i\), and \(Q^i_j\) the quantity of good \(j\) produced by person \(i\) and \(Q^i_j\) the quantity of good \(j\) produced by person \(i\). (Imagine they both work 4 hours).
  • Let \(a^i_j\) denote the so-called labor input coefficients, that is, the units of labor required by a person \(i \in \{A,B\}\) to produce one unit of good \(j\in \{x,y\}\).
  • Suppose further that person B requires fewer units of labor to produce both goods, that is, \(a^A_y>a^B_y\) and \(a^A_x>a^B_x\), and that
  • a comparative advantage exists, that is, \(\frac{a^B_y}{a^B_x} \neq \frac{a^A_y}{a^A_x}\).

Ricardian theorem

If each country specialize in the production in the good for which it has a comparative advantage and exports this good, both countries gain from trade when the new world market price relation, \(\frac{p^*_y}{p^*_x}\), lies between the price relations of both countries3 \[\begin{align*} \frac{a^B_y}{a^B_x} = \frac{p^B_y}{p^B_x} &> \frac{a^*_y}{a^*_x}= \frac{p^*_y}{p^*_x}> \frac{p^A_y}{p^A_x} = \frac{a^A_y}{a^A_x} \end{align*}\] because the consumption possibilities enlarge for both countries compared to a situation with no trade.

3 In order to see that the relative prices within a country equals the relative productivity parameters, consider that nominal income of labor in producing good \(j\in \{x,y\}\), \(w_jL^i_j\), must equal the production value, that is, \(p_j^ix_j^i\): \[ w_jL^i_j=p_j^ix_j^i. \] Setting \(w_j=1\) as the numeraire and re-arranging the equation, we get \[ p_j^i=\frac{L_j^i}{x_j^i}=a_j^i. \]

21.4 Distribution of welfare gains

The Ricardo theorem tells us nothing about the precise distribution of welfare gains. In this section, I will show that the distribution of welfare gains is the result of relative supply and demand in the world.

To illustrate this, consider Ricardo’s famous example4 of two countries (England and Portugal) that can produce cloth \(T\) and wine \(W\) with different input requirements, namely:

4 The example is explained by Suranovic (2012) in greater detail.

Suranovic, S. (2012). International economics: Theory and policy (1.0 ed.). Saylor Foundation. https://open.umn.edu/opentextbooks/textbooks/276

\[\begin{align*} \frac{p^P_W}{p^P_T}=\frac{a^P_W}{a^P_T}=\frac{8}{9}<\frac{12}{10}=\frac{a^E_W}{a^E_T}= \frac{p^E_W}{p^E_T} \end{align*}\] Thus, England has an absolute disadvantage in the production of both goods, but England has a comparative advantage in the production of cloth and Portugal has a comparative advantage in the production of wine. Let us further assume that both countries are similarly endowed with labor, \(\bar{L}\). Then we can calculate the world supply of cloth and wine given relative world prices, \(\frac{p_T}{p_W}\). Since we know that Portugal will only produce wine if the price of wine relative to cloth is above \(\frac{p_W}{p_T}=\frac{8}{9}\) and England will only produce wine if the price of wine relative to cloth is above \(\frac{p_W}{p_T}=\frac{12}{10}\), we can draw the relative world supply of goods as shown in the left panel of Figure 21.8. Note that \(\alpha\) in the figure means \(\frac{1}{a}\). Similarly, we can draw in the world supply of clothes, shown in the left panel of Figure 21.8.

Figure 21.8: World’s relative supply

Whether both countries specialize totally in the production of one good, or only one country does so depends on world demand for both goods at relative prices. Since we know from the Ricardo Theorem that the world market price relation, \(\frac{p^{*}_T}{p^{*}_W}\), must be between the two autarky price relations: \[\begin{align} \frac{p^P_T}{p^P_W}>\frac{p^{*}_T}{p^{*}_W}> \frac{p^E_T}{p^E_W}. \end{align}\] If world demand for cloth would be sufficiently high to have a world price of \[\frac{p^P_T}{p^P_W}=\frac{9}{8}\] Portugal would not gain from trade. On the contrary, if world demand for wine would be sufficiently high to have a world price of \[\frac{p^P_T}{p^P_W}=\frac{10}{12}\] England would not gain from trade. Thus, the price span between \(\frac{10}{12}\) and \(\frac{9}{8}\) says us which country gains from trade. For example, at a world price of \[\frac{p^{*}_T}{p^{*}_W}=1\] about 57%
\[\begin{align} \left[\frac{\left(1-\frac{10}{12}\right)}{\left(\frac{9}{8}-\frac{10}{12}\right)}\approx 0.57 \right] \end{align}\] of the gains through trade will be distributed to Portugal and about 43% will be distributed to England.

In Figure 21.9, I show two demand curves of the World. The dashed demand curve represents a world with a relative strong preference on wine and the other demand curve represents a relative strong demand for cloth. Since Portugal has a comparative advantage in producing wine, they would happy to live in a world where demand for wine is relatively high, whereas the opposite holds true for England.

Figure 21.9: World’s relative supply and demand

Exercise 21.2 Comparative advantage and opportunity costs

Assume that only two countries, A and B, exist. Both countries are equally endowed with labor which is the only production factor. Both countries can produce either good \(y\) or good \(x\). The table below gives the input coefficients, \(a\), for both countries, that is, the units of labor needed to produce one unit of good \(y\) and good \(x\), respectively. Assume that both countries have 12 units of labor available.

Country A Country B
Good y 1 3
Good x 2 4
  1. Name the country with an absolute advantage.
  2. Draw the production possibility curves in a y-x-diagramm.
  3. What are opportunity costs?
  4. Calculate how many goods of \(x\) country A has to give up to produce one unit more of good \(y\).
  5. Calculate how many goods of \(y\) country A has to give up to produce one unit more of good \(x\).
  6. Calculate how many goods of \(x\) country B has to give up to produce one unit more of good \(y\).
  7. Calculate how many goods of \(y\) country B has to give up to produce one unit more of good \(x\).
  8. Name the country with a comparative advantage in good \(y\).
  9. Name the country with a comparative advantage in good \(x\).
  1. Country A has an absolute advantage in producing both goods as \[ a_y^A=1<3=a_y^B \] and \[ a_x^A=2<4=a_x^B \]
  2. Solution is shown in the lecture.
  3. Opportunity cost is the value of what you lose when choosing between two or more options. Alternative definition: Opportunity cost is the loss you take to make a gain, or the loss of one gain for another gain.
  4. If A wants to produce one unit more of good \(y\) it has to give up \(\frac{1}{2}\) units of good \(x\).
  5. If A wants to produce one unit more of good \(x\) it has to give up \(2\) units of good \(y\).
  6. If B wants to produce one unit more of good \(y\) it has to give up \(\frac{3}{4}\) units of good \(x\).
  7. If A wants to produce one unit more of good \(x\) it has to give up \(\frac{4}{3}\) units of good \(y\).
opportunity costs of producing … A B
…1 unit of good \(y\) \(\frac{a_y^A}{a_x^A}=\frac{1}{2}=0.5\) (good x) \(\frac{a_y^B}{a_x^B}=\frac{3}{4}\) (good x)
…1 unit of good \(x\) \(\frac{a_x^A}{a_y^A}=\frac{2}{1}=2\) (good y) \(\frac{a_x^B}{a_y^B}=\frac{4}{3}=\) (good y)
  1. Country A has a comparative advantage in producing good \(y\).
  2. Country B has a comparative advantage in producing good \(x\).

Exercise 21.3 The best industry is not competitive

Assume that only two countries, A and B, exist. Both countries are equally endowed with labor which is the only production factor. Both countries can produce either good \(y\) or good \(x\). The table below gives the input coefficients, \(a\), for both countries, that is, the units of labor needed to produce one unit of good \(y\) and good \(x\), respectively.

Good Country A Country B
Good y 10 9
Good x 12 10

Discuss absolute and comparative advantages. How much faster does B needs to in producing good \(y\) to become an exporter of that good?

The logic of opportunity cost is straightforward. You must compare the opportunity costs across countries: If country A wants to produce one more unit of good \(y\), it requires 10 units of labor. With these 10 units, it could produce 10/12 = 0.83 units of good \(x\) because it requires 12 units of labor to produce 1 unit of good \(x\). If country B wants to produce one more unit of good \(y\), it requires 9 units of labor. With these 9 units, it could produce 9/10 = 0.9 units of good \(x\) because it requires 10 units of labor to produce 1 unit of good \(x\). Thus, the opportunity costs of country A are smaller compared to country B in producing good \(y\). This is because country A has to give up less production of good \(x\) in order to produce 1 more unit of good \(y\).

opportunity costs of producing… Person A Person B
…1 unit of good y: \(\frac{a_y^A}{a_x^A} = \frac{10}{12} \approx 0.83\) (good x) \(\frac{a_y^B}{a_x^B} = \frac{9}{10} = 0.9\) (good x)
…1 unit of good x: \(\frac{a_x^A}{a_y^A} = \frac{12}{10} = 1.2\) (good y) \(\frac{a_x^B}{a_y^B} = \frac{10}{9} \approx 1.11\) (good y)

Thus, A has a comparative advantage in producing good \(y\) and B has a comparative advantage in producing good \(x\). This seems to be counterintuitive as B can produce faster anything and everybody else.

When looking on input coefficients, we get \[ \frac{a^A_y}{a^A_x}=\frac{10}{12} < \frac{9}{10}=\frac{a^B_y}{a^B_x} \] which gives us the same comparative advantages as described above.

To become an exporter of \(y\), B needs to have lower opportunity costs in the production of \(y\) than A. This can happen by becoming more productive in producing \(y\) and/or by becoming ‘slower’ in producing good \(x\) so that \(\frac{a_y^B}{a_x^B}<\frac{10}{12}\)

Exercise 21.4 Comparative advantage and input coefficients

Assume that only two countries, A and B, exist. Both countries are equally endowed with labor which is the only production factor. Both countries can produce either good \(y\) or good \(x\). The table below gives the input coefficients, \(a\), for both countries, that is, the units of labor needed to produce one unit of good \(y\) and good \(x\), respectively.

Country A Country B
Good y 400 2
Good x 300 1
  1. Name the country with an absolute advantage.
  2. Name the country with a comparative advantage in good \(y\).
  3. Name the country with a comparative advantage in good \(x\).
  1. Country B has an absolute advantage in producing both goods.
  2. Country A has a comparative advantage in producing good \(y\).
  3. Country B has a comparative advantage in producing good \(x\).

Exercise 21.5 Comparative advantage: Germany and Bangladesh

The table below gives the unit of labor needed to produce one machine, one ship, and one cloth in Germany and Bangladesh.

Machine Ship Cloth
Bangladesh 100 10000 50
Germany 5 50 3
  1. Which country has an absolute advantage in the production of machines, ships, and clothes?
  2. What is Germany’s and Bangladesh’s comparative advantage if we look only at machines and ships?
  3. What is Germany’s and Bangladesh’s comparative advantage if we look only at machines and clothes?
  4. What is Germany’s and Bangladesh’s comparative advantage if we look only at ships and clothes?
  5. Can you infer from the previous calculations which good Germany will export for sure and which good it will surely not export?
  1. Germany has an absolute advantage in the production of the three goods because it labor input coefficients are smaller in all three goods.
  2. Since \(p^{m/s}_B=\frac{100}{10000}<p^{m/s}_G=\frac{5}{50}\) Bangladesh has a comparative advantage in producing machines and Germany has a comparative advantage in producing ships.
  3. Since \(p^{m/c}_B=\frac{100}{50}>p^{m/c}_G=\frac{5}{3}\) Bangladesh has a comparative advantage in producing clothes and Germany has a comparative advantage in producing machines.
  4. Since \(p^{s/c}_B=\frac{10000}{50}>p^{s/c}_G=\frac{50}{3}\) Bangladesh has a comparative advantage in producing clothes and Germany has a comparative advantage in producing ships.
  5. Germany has a clear comparative advantage in producing ships and hence will export ships. Moreover, Germany has a clear comparative disadvantage in producing cloth and will definitely import clothes.

Exercise 21.6 Multiple choice: Ricardian model

Assume that only two countries, A and B, exist. Both countries are equally endowed with labor which is the only production factor. Both countries can produce either good \(y\) or good \(x\). The table below gives the input coefficients, \(a\), for both countries, that is, the units of labor needed to produce one unit of good \(y\) and good \(x\), respectively.

Country A Country B
Good y 40 20
Good x 30 10

Which of the following statements is/are true?

  1. Country A has an absolute advantage in producing both goods.
  2. Country B has an absolute advantage in producing both goods.
  3. Country A has a comparative advantage in good \(y\) and a comparative disadvantage in good \(x\).
  4. Country B has a comparative advantage in good \(y\) and a comparative disadvantage in good \(x\).
  5. Trade will not occur between these two countries.

Choices b) and c) are correct.

Exercise 21.7 Ricardian Model again

Assume that only two countries, A and B, exist. Both countries are equally endowed with the only production factor labor which can be used to produce either good \(y\) or good \(x\). The table below gives input coefficients, \(a\), for both countries, that is, the units of labor needed to produce one unit of good \(y\) and good \(x\), respectively.

Country A Country B
Good \(y\) 11 22
Good \(x\) 8 16

Which of the following statements is true?

  1. Country A will export good \(y\) and import good \(x\).
  2. Country B will export good \(y\) and import good \(x\).
  3. Country B has an absolute disadvantage in producing both goods.
  4. Trade will not occur between these two countries.
  1. and d) are true.

Exercise 21.8 Bike and tires

Consider two countries, \(A\) and \(B\). Both have a labor endowment of 24, \(L^A=L^B=24\). In both countries two goods can be produced: bikes, which are denoted by \(y\), and bike tires, which are denoted by \(x\). Assume that the two goods can only be consumed in bundles of one bike and two bike tires. The following graph illustrates the production possibility (PPF) curve of both countries in autarky, i.e, country A and B do not trade with each other.

Figure 21.10: Production possibilities of bike and tires in A and B
  1. How many complete bikes, that is, one bike with two tires, can be consumed in autarky in country A and B, respectively. Draw the production points for country A and B into the figure. (A calculation is not necessary.)
  2. Calculate —for both countries—the input coefficients, \(a\), that is, the units of labor needed to produce one unit of good \(y\) and good \(x\), respectively. Fill in the four input coefficients in the following table:
Country A Country B
Good y (bikes) (\(~~~~~~~\)) (\(~~~~~~~\))
Good x (bike tires) (\(~~~~~~~\)) (\(~~~~~~~\))
  1. Fill in the ten gaps (\(~~~~~~~\)) in the following text:

If we assume that both countries specialize completely in the production of the good at which they have a comparative advantage and trade is allowed and free of costs, then

  • country A produces (\(~~~~~~~\)) units of bikes and (\(~~~~~~~\)) units of tires and

  • country B produces (\(~~~~~~~\)) units of bikes and (\(~~~~~~~\)) units of tires.

Moreover, since both countries aim to consume complete bikes, that is, one bike with two tires,

  • country A exports (\(~~~~~~~\)) units of (\(~~~~~~~\)) and imports (\(~~~~~~~\)) units of (\(~~~~~~~\)) and

  • country B exports (\(~~~~~~~\)) units of (\(~~~~~~~\)) and imports (\(~~~~~~~\)) units of (\(~~~~~~~\)).

Under free trade - country A can consume (\(~~~~~~~\)) complete bikes and - country B can consume (\(~~~~~~~\)) complete bikes.

  1. Both countries can consume 2 complete bikes, see Figure 21.11.
Figure 21.11: Production and consumption in A and B
Country A Country B
Good \(y\) (bikes) 24:6=4 24:3=8
Good \(x\) (bike tires) 24:8=3 24:12=2
  1. If we assume that both countries specialize completely in the production of the good at which they have a comparative advantage and trade is allowed and free of costs, then
  • country A produces 6 units of bikes and 0 units of tires and
  • country B produces 0 units of bikes and 12 units of tires.

Moreover, since both countries aim to consume complete bikes, i.e., one bike with two tires,

  • country A exports 3 units of bikes and imports 6 units of tires and
  • country B exports 6 units of tires and imports 3 units of bikes.

Under free trade

  • country A can consume 3 complete bikes and
  • country B can consume 3 complete bikes.

Exercise 21.9 Ricardian model MC

Assume that only two countries, A and B, exist. Both countries are equally endowed with the only production factor labor which can be used to produce either good \(y\) or good \(x\). The table below gives input coefficients, \(a\), for both countries, that is, the units of labor needed to produce one unit of good \(y\) and good \(x\), respectively.

Country A Country B
Good \(y\) 321 899
Good \(x\) 459 999

Which of the following statements is true?

  1. Country A has an absolute advantage in both goods.
  2. Country A has an absolute advantage in good \(y\)
  3. Country A has a comparative advantage in both goods.
  4. Country B has a comparative advantage in both goods.
  5. Country A has a comparative advantage in good \(y\).
  6. Country B has a comparative advantage in good \(y\).

a), b), and e) are correct statements.